Carbon Tax and Emissions Trading

 

                                                                            

 

Some of the issues surrounding carbon tax are introduced in a short factsheet from the International Transport Worker’s Federation (ITF, n.d.). Carbon taxes are described as a ‘market solution’ intended to reduce CO2 emissions by making it more expensive to produce them. An example of how this might work is that fossil fuel companies would be taxed on the basis of their emissions, and would then pass the cost on to their customers, resulting in reduced consumption of the goods and services the companies provide. The main argument advanced against carbon tax is that the poor would suffer most from price increases, for example in the cost of heating, while the behaviour of wealthier people might well be unaffected; the tax is thus considered regressive. A fairer way to reduce CO2 emissions would be through government actions such as a program of house insulation. The article concludes that despite the unfairness of carbon taxes, there is still a strong argument for them in view of the financial restraints on governments, the urgent need to cut emissions, and the likelihood that if they are not reduced, working people and the poor will suffer far more than the rich. These and related issues will be examined in more detail below.

Carbon taxes have been described alongside other “mechanisms that force polluters to pay for the climate damage done by their product” (Mann, 2021, p.99). Whereas a carbon tax “is levied at the point of sale on the carbon content of fuels or any other product yielding greenhouse emissions”, tradable emissions permits are sold or allocated in limited quantities by governments, and the “polluters can buy or sell these permits” to pollute. A third mechanism is provided by carbon credits, “granted for activities that take carbon out of the atmosphere and bury or store it”.

The World Bank considers that there are “several paths governments can take to price carbon” in order that the “external costs of carbon emissions” such as damage to the environment and health and the effects of drought and sea level rise should be tied to those who are responsible for emissions, and who can reduce them. The two main methods are emissions trading systems (ETS) and carbon taxes. Emissions trading systems are also known as cap-and-trade systems since they place an upper limit on permitted greenhouse gas emissions, and allow “those industries with low emissions to sell their extra allowances to larger emitters.” This process “establishes a market price for greenhouse gas emissions.” A carbon tax differs from an ETS in that it directly sets a pre-defined price on greenhouse gas emissions or on the carbon content of fossil fuels. “The choice of the instrument will depend on national and economic circumstance” and some “40 countries and more than 20 cities, states and provinces already use carbon pricing mechanisms, with more planning to implement them in the future” (The World Bank, 2020).

An article which appeared in the Wall Street Journal early in 2019, was subsequently published as the “Economists’ Statement on Carbon Dividends organised by the Climate Leadership Council” (Econstatement, 2019). It recommends a carbon tax as “the most cost-effective lever to reduce carbon emissions at the scale and speed that is necessary.” The tax should “increase every year until emissions reductions goals are met and be revenue neutral to avoid debates over the size of government.” Such a tax, if sufficiently robust, would “replace the need for various carbon regulations that are less efficient.” Two further recommendations are advanced in the context of the USA, though they may well also apply to other countries: a border carbon adjustment system should be established to prevent carbon leakage and to protect national competitiveness; and all the revenue from the tax should be rebated directly to citizens as lump-sums. The Climate Leadership Council, based in Washington, describes itself as an international policy institute aiming to “promote a carbon dividends framework as the most cost-effective, equitable and politically-viable climate solution” (CLC, 2021).

Commenting on the Economists’ Statement on Carbon Dividends, Chomsky and Pollin (2020, p. 22) note that while its authors propose to redistribute revenue from the carbon tax to the population in equal shares to protect the poor from cost-of-living increases, “these economists offer no support for increases in public investments in renewable energy and energy efficiency”, but oppose regulations that require electrical utilities to stop burning coal, positions which they see as “massive policy errors”. However, they acknowledge that the “orthodox economists” who signed the 2019 statement “are clear that government intervention is necessary to force capitalists to integrate the costs of environmental destruction into their calculations” (p.67). Chomsky and Pollin have in mind global solutions to the global problem of climate change, with some form of carbon tax with rebates playing an important role alongside other measures such as the elimination of all fossil fuel subsidies, a Green Bond lending program initiated by the US Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank, and funds reallocated from worldwide military budgets. Together with private investments, a total of $2.4 trillion should be reached in 2021, representing about 0.7% of total global financial assets (p.104). Carbon tax is envisaged as beginning at around $20 per ton of carbon in 2024 (p. 105), and revenues would contribute about $160 billion to the total (p.108). A simple global rebate scheme would give about $60 to everyone on earth significantly raising the income of the poorest; but Individual governments would adjust distribution within their populations (p.111). A substantial portion of total funds would be invested in clean energy projects.

Helm (2020) is no doubt thinking mainly of the developed nations when he writes that “the root cause of climate change is … our unsustainable carbon lifestyles” and that if we pay for the pollution that we cause “our standard of living will be impacted” (p.xv). He argues that without a price on the pollution that causes climate change, there is no incentive to reduce it (p.84) and points out that every “company in the FT100 index is embedded in the fossil fuel economy” (p.26). In his view “a pragmatic climate change policy” involves three interventions: making polluters pay; providing public funding for public goods; and ensuring that damage is compensated for by requiring net environmental gain”. These actions can be unilateral, and do not require international agreements, “provided the price of pollution is generalised to include imports” (p.105). Carbon pricing is collective, does not involve moral persuasion, and Helm believes that done properly it can be a bottom-up approach which “incentivises other countries to follow suit” (p.106). However he acknowledges serious difficulties: in the UK the political left sees the carbon tax as regressive and favours progressive taxation of wealth and income, with regulation as the method of controlling pollution (p.102).  There are also ethical problems, since a carbon price can be seen as a license to pollute (p.107ff). However, the flaws in carbon pricing “pale into insignificance when compared to those of regulation” which is open to lobbying by vested interests (p.109).

Attempts to set a price for carbon using cost benefit analysis have yielded a wide range of results “from less than $10 per tonne to more than $200” (pp. 113-4). This is perhaps not surprising since the damaging effects of climate change vary greatly from one part of the world to another. “An immediately high price will yield lots of money … but not much in the way of actual carbon reductions” and Helm stresses the advantages of setting a low initial price, and increasing it over the next thirty years to achieve the climate target of net zero (p.115).

A carbon tax aimed at eliminating the contribution of a country to global warming must be on consumption and not merely on production, and this necessitates a carbon border tax. The objections to such a tax are listed by Helm as the resulting increase in the cost of living; the difficulty of measuring the carbon content of many imports; and the supposed illegality of such a tax under World Trade Organisation rules. On the first point Helm accepts that we simply have to reduce our consumption; on the second he argues that a rough approximation to carbon content would be acceptable; and on the third he proposes that WTO rules on “environmental adjustments” could accommodate the tax. In an earlier work he claimed that “the carbon border tax does not need an international agreement … With a carbon tax in place … the market would then be properly incentivized to start the serious business of decarbonizing” (Helm, 2012, p. 194).

Mann (op. cit.) provides examples of the effectiveness of carbon pricing policies, the sources and methods of opposition to them, and issues concerning regression, rebate and the law. He cites the International Monetary fund as supporting carbon pricing, and as recommending an average price of $75 per ton in order to meet the Paris Agreement goal of keeping global warming below 2°C.  An amendment to the U.S Clean Air Act of 1990 is referred to as an example of effective action against atmospheric pollution: a cap-and-trade policy “required coal-fired power plants to scrub sulfur emissions before they exited smokestacks” (p.100). These emissions fell by 36% in the subsequent 14 years while power output rose by 25%. The emissions trading scheme implemented in Australia by Prime Minister Julia Gillard in 2012 is described as resulting in emissions reductions in the electricity sector of “more than 9% during the first six months of implementation” (p.100), but was eventually revoked (p.104).

Opposition to carbon pricing can come from sources such as fossil fuel interests and right wing politicians: “to make a price on carbon toxic, all they have to do is to associate it with social unrest, disruption and economic pain” (p.107). However “carbon pricing has been vulnerable not just to attacks from the right, but also to attacks from the left”; it has been portrayed by some progressives as “an ostensible mechanism of neoliberal economics that discounts social justice” (p.108). An example of opposition from an environmental movement to a carbon reduction policy is provided by the vote by Australia’s Green Party against the 2009 Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme on the grounds that it was not sufficiently ambitious (p.111).

Mann argues that “whether a carbon tax is progressive or regressive depends on how it is designed” (p.108), that it is not intrinsically divisive and that it can return revenue to “the poor and those most impacted” through appropriate design. He claims that “Americans in general support carbon pricing by a four-to-one margin” (p. 231), and that moderate conservatives are “on board with climate action”, in contrast with the “deniers, delayers and deflectors” (p.117). He cites David Cameron in the UK who “implored his fellow conservatives not to abandon” climate change and the future of the planet, which were natural conservative issues which the left would approach with anti-business, anti-enterprise and anti-technology responses (p. 117). The belief that the introduction of a carbon tax would shield the fossil fuel companies from legal liability for their actions is challenged by Mann, who refers to current lawsuits against the fossil fuel companies, drawing comparison with earlier action against the tobacco industry which hid the dangers of its activities from the public (p.109).

 

References

Chomsky, N. and Pollin, R., 2020, The climate crisis and the global green new deal: the political economy of saving the planet.  London and New York: Verso Books.

CLC, 2021, The Climate Leadership Council, website accessed 3 April 2021

https://clcouncil.org

Econstatement, 2019, “Economists’ Statement on Carbon Dividends organised by the Climate Leadership Council”, online, accessed 30 March 2021 https://www.econstatement.org

Helm, D., 2012, The carbon crunch: how we’re getting climate change wrong – and how to fix it. New Haven and London: Yale University Press

Helm, D., 2020, Net zero: how we stop causing climate change. London: William Collins.

ITF, n.d., “Factsheet 13: Controversies – carbon taxes”, International Transport Worker’s Federation, online, accessed 30 March 2021

https://www.itfglobal.org/media/658254/ITF-factsheet-13-Controversies-–-carbon-taxes.pdf

Mann, M.E., 2021, The new climate war. London and Brunswick: Scribe Publications.

World Bank, 2020, “Pricing Carbon”, The World Bank, online, accessed 2 April 2021

https://www.worldbank.org/en/programs/pricing-carbon

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Energy maps and calculators

Carbon Capture, Utilization and Storage

Climate fiction and climate action